Another Reason to Move the Supply Chain

This time for the Republic of China’s Foxconn, which among other things, assembles iPhones in a People’s Republic of China factory in Zhengzhou.

In Foxconn’s main Zhengzhou facility, the world’s biggest assembly site for Apple Inc’s iPhones, hundreds of thousands of workers have been placed under a closed-loop system for almost two weeks. They are largely shut off from the outside world, allowed only to move between their dorms or homes and the production lines.

The mainland Chinese workers are causing their own problems for Foxconn, also.

“It’s too dangerous to go to work,” a 21-year-old worker who has been confined to his dorm told The Wall Street Journal, saying that he was skeptical about the company’s claim that there was a low level of infections at the plant.

And

Some workers interviewed by the Journal said many colleagues had refused to go back to the production lines. Others had simply left, they said, sometimes abandoning their belongings.

And

Another Foxconn employee said most of his dozen-strong team of night-shift workers had either been taken to a quarantine facility or had refused to return to work. ….
“I don’t know who around me is a positive case,” said the worker, who has been confined to his dorm for a few days. “I’d be better off staying in the dorm.”

For good reasons or ill, the bottom line is that Foxconn cannot rely on its mainland collection of employees, much less the PRC government’s capricious responses to its Wuhan Virus situation.

Foxconn would be much better off to move its production/assembly facility back to the Republic of China, or to Vietnam, or to expand its nascent production/assembly facility in the US, or some combination of the three. The transition will be expensive, of course, but only in the short-term. Intermediate- and long-term, the company will be much better off, with a more reliable and stable work force, and so will Foxconn’s customers be.

Interest Rates and Inflation

The Fed is trying to fight inflation and to reduce it by raising interest rates (I’m omitting the Progressive-Democratic Party-controlled Congress’ and White House’s countervailing profligate spending that fuels inflation). There are growing questions regarding how fast the Fed should raise rates after its last few .75% rate increases. As The Wall Street Journal noted, that debate tends to obscure a related and more important argument over how high rates need to go in the end in order to halt the current inflation (and reduce inflation to a more manageable and historically targeted rate of 2%).

Some officials have argued for slowing the pace of rate rises after this week’s meeting. But the debate over the speed of increases could obscure a more important one around how high rates ultimately rise.

But the discussion as a whole misses another factor impacting market interest rates: the private—nonbank—market in lending. These entities are private individuals or private companies outside the traditional financial industry—banks, investment banks, credit unions—who extend loans (in the context of this post) to companies. These private lenders mostly lend into the housing industry (which is falling on interest rate-driven hard times), but in today’s environment they’re branching out.

The question of private lending matters here because in order to make the loans—and so to make money—the private lender must offer terms more favorable to the borrower than the banks offer (keeping in mind that what banks can offer is heavily influenced by the Fed). The private lender’s terms can center on a variety of parameters—loan period, collateral required, and so on, as can the bank’s—but the primary parameter is the interest rate demanded. That private lender rate must be lower than the bank’s rate, or the borrower will stay with the bank.

The private lenders’ lower rates mitigate the Fed’s efforts to fight inflation with rising interest rates. There are two aspects to this conflict. One is that rising interest rates are intrinsically inflationary—they drive up the cost of money and so of prices. Private lender competition through interest rates would seem to be counter-inflationary. However, the inflationary impact of rising rates takes time to develop, while the counter-inflationary impact of rising rates is relatively immediate: that immediate increase in the cost of money reduces producers’ nearby demand for goods and services, which reduces cost for producers’ goods and services, and that percolates through to reduced consumer prices—the inflation consumers face—relatively quickly.

The other aspect is how large a role private lending plays in the loan/borrower market, and so how much conflict there really is between the Feds’ need to raise rates to kill excessive inflation and the private lenders’ playing into this new market niche of bank vs private lending with lower rates. That’s unknown, so far; the expansion of private lending is a new, investment technology- and communications technology-driven phenomenon.

And this whole discussion, including mine, doesn’t account for venture capital investing, including SPAC investing, which is glorified lending: these entities invest in small (usually) companies. Usually, the investments are with a view to the company growing and with that value increment, the venture capitalists and the subgroup that is SPACs get their investment back.

But often, those investments are loans, or have serious loan components, with the company as collateral: the investors get the company if the loan isn’t repaid, or by design of the loan component, the repayment is the company. Such venture capital “lending” dilutes the lending market as a whole, and so tends to weaken the impact of Fed actions to the extent that dilution grows.